________________________________________________________________________________________
CHAPTER III
THE SILVER STANDARD AND THE EVILS OF ITS INSTABILITY
The economic consequences of this rupture of
the par of exchange were of the most far-reaching character. It divided the commercial
world into two sharply defined groups, one using gold and the other using silver as their
standard money. When so much gold was always equal to so much silver, as was the case
previous to 1873, it mattered very little, for the purposes of international transactions, whether a country was on a gold or on
a silver standard ; nor did it make any difference in which
of the two currencies its obligations were stipulated and realised. But when, owing to the
dislocation of the fixed par, it was not possible to define how much silver was equal to
how much gold from year to year or even from month to month, this precision of value, the
very soul of pecuniary exchange, gave place to the uncertainties of gambling. Of course,
all countries were not drawn into this vortex of perplexities in the same degree and to
the same extent, yet it was impossible for any country
which participated in international commerce to escape from being dragged into it. This
was true of India as it was of no other country. She was a silver-standard country
intimately bound to a gold-standard country, so that her economic and financial life was
at the mercy of blind forces operating upon the relative values of gold and silver which
governed the rupee-sterling exchange.
The fall increased the burden of those who were under an obligation to make gold payments. Amongst such, the most heavily charged was the Government of India. Owing to the exigencies of its political constitution, that Government has been under the necessity of making certain payments in England to meet : (1) interest on debt and on the stock of the guaranteed railway companies ; (2) expenses on account of the European troops maintained in India; (3) pensions and non-effective allowances payable in England; (4) cost of the home administration[f1]; and (5) stores purchased in England for use or consumption in India. England being a gold-standard country, these payments were necessarily gold payments. But the revenues of the Government of India out of which these payments were met were received in silver, which was the sole legal-tender money of the country. It is evident that even if the gold payments were a fixed quantity their burden must increase pan passu with the fall in the gold value of silver. But the gold payments were not a fixed quantity. They have ever been on the increase, so that the rupee cost of the gold payments grew both by reason of the growth in their magnitude, and also by reason of the contraction of the medium, i.e. the appreciation of gold, in which they were payable. How greatly this double levy diminished the revenues of India, the figures in Table XI give a convincing testimony.
TABLE XI
increase IN THE rupee
cost oF gold PAYMENTS[f2]
Financial Year |
Average Rate of Exchange
for the Year |
Total Excess of Rupees
needed to provide for the net Sterling Payments of the Year over those required to meet
the Sterling Payments of 1874-75 |
Amount of this Excess due
to |
|
|
|
|
(1) Fall in the Rate of
Exchange over that of 1874-75 |
(2) Increase in gold payments over those of
the Year 1874-75 |
|
R |
R |
||
1875-76 |
1 9.626 |
86,97,980 |
41,13,723 |
45,84,257 |
1876-77 |
1 8.508 |
3,15,06,824 |
1,44,68,234 |
1,70,38,590 |
1877-78 |
1 8.791 |
1,30,05,481 |
1,14,58,670 |
1,15,46,811 |
1878-79 |
1 7.794 |
1,85,23,170 |
1,04,16,718 |
81,06,452 |
1879-80 |
1 7.961 |
39,23,570 |
1,65,37,394 |
-1,26,13,824 |
1880-81 |
1 7.956 |
3,12,11,981 |
1,92,82,582 |
1,19,29,399 |
1881-82 |
1 7.895 |
3,18,19,685 |
1,98,76,786 |
-1,19,42,899 |
1882-83 |
1 7.525 |
62,50,518 |
1,86,35,246 |
2,48,85,764 |
1883-84 |
1 7.536 |
3,44,16,685 |
2,33,46,040 |
1,10,70,645 |
1884-85 |
1 7.308 |
1,96,25,981 |
2,48,03,423 |
51,77,442 |
1885-86 |
1 6.254 |
1,82,11,346 |
2,54,95,337 |
-4,37,06,683 |
1886-87 |
1 5.441 |
4,69,16,788 |
4,46,68,299 |
22,48,489 |
1887-88 |
1 4.898 |
4,63,13,161 |
4,96,60,537 |
- 33,47,376 |
1888-89 |
1 4.379 |
9,00,38,166 |
6,59,71,998 |
2,40,66,168 |
1889-90 |
1 4.566 |
7,75,96,889 |
6,06,98,370 |
1,68,98,519 |
1890-91 |
1 6.090 |
9,06,11,857 |
4,65,48,302 |
4,40,63,555 |
1891-92 |
1 4.733 |
10,44,44,529 |
6,54,52,999 |
3,89,91,530 |
The effect of such a growing burden on the
finance of the Government may well be imagined; the
condition of the Government, embarrassing at first, later
became quite desperate under this continuously increasing burden. It enforced a policy of
high taxation and rigid economy in the finances of the Government. Analysing the resource
side of the Indian Budgets from the year 1872-73, we find that there was hardly any year
which did not expire without making an addition to the existing imposts of the country. In
1872-73, there commenced the levy of what were called Provincial Rates. The fiscal year
1875-76 witnessed the addition of R. 1 per gallon in the
excise duty on spirits. In 1877-78 the Pass Duty on Malwa
opium was raised from Rs. 600 to Rs.
650 per chest. An addition of a License Tax and Local Rates was made in the year 1878-79,
and an increase of Rs. 50 per chest took place in the Malwa Opium Duty in the following
year. With the help of these imposts the Government expected to place its finances on an
adequate basis. By the end of 1882, it felt quite secure and even went so far as to remit
some of the taxes, which it did by lowering the customs duties and the Patwari Cess in the North-Western Provinces. But the rapid
pace in the fall of the exchange soon showed that a resort to further taxation was
necessary to make up for the increased cost of the sterling payments. To the existing
burdens, therefore, was added in 1886 an Income Tax, a duty of 5 per cent. on imported and
also on non-illuminating petroleum. The Salt Duty was raised in 1888 in India from Rs. 2
to Rs. 2 1/2 and in Burma from 3 annas to R. 1 per maund. The
Patwari Cess of the North-Western Provinces, repealed in 1882, was re-imposed in 1888. The
rates of duty on imported spirit and the excise duties on spirits were not only raised in
1890, but were afterwards added to in every province. An excise duty on malt liquor was
levied in 1893, and another on salted fish at the rate of 6 annas per maund. The yield of
the taxes and duties levied from 1882-83 was[f3] as follows:
Sources |
1882-83 |
1892-93 |
|
Rs. |
Rs. |
Salt Excise Customs Assessed Taxes |
5,67,50,000 3,47,50,000
1,08,90,000 48,40,000 |
8,14,90,000 4,97,90,000
1,41,80,000 1,63,60,000 |
All this additional burden was due to the
enhanced cost of meeting the gold payments, and "would not have been necessary but
for the fall in the exchange."[f4]
Along with this increase of resources the
Government of India also exercised the virtue of economy in the cost of administration.
For the first time in its history, the Government turned to the alternative of employing
the comparatively cheaper agency of the natives of the country in place of the imported
Englishmen. Prior to 1870, the scope of effecting economy along this line was very
limited. By the Civil Service Reforms of 1853[f5] the way was cleared for the appointment of
Indians to the posts reserved by the Statute of 1793[f6] for the members of the covenanted Civil
Service. But this reform did not conduce to any economy in the cost of the administration,
because the Indian members carried the same high scale of salaries as did the English
members of the Civil Service. It was when the Statute of 1870 (33 Vic. c. 3) was passed permitting the appointment by nomination of
non-covenanted Indians to places reserved for the covenanted Civil Service on a lower
scale of salary, that a real scope for economy presented itself to the Government of
India. Hard pressed, the Government of India availed itself of the possibilities for
economy held out by this statute. So great was
the need for economy and so powerful was the interest of the Government in reducing its
expenditure that it proceeded, notwithstanding increased demands for efficient
administration, to substitute the less expensive agency of non-covenanted civilians in
place of the more expensive agency of the covenanted civilians. The scale on which this
substitution was effected was by no means small, for we find that between 1874 and 1889
the strength of the covenanted service recruited in England was reduced by more than 22
per cent., and was further expected to be reduced by about
12 per cent., by the employment of unconvenanted Indians to the posts usually reserved for
covenanted civilians [f7]. Besides substituting a cheap for a dear
agency in the administration, the Government also sought to obtain relief by applying the
pruning knife to the rank growth in departmental extravagances.[f8] Even with such heroic efforts to increase the
revenue and reduce the expenditure the finances of the Government throughout the period of
the falling exchange were never in a flourishing state, as is shown in Table XII.
Much more regrettable was the inability of the
Government, owing to its financial difficulties, to find money for useful public works.
The welfare of the Indian people depends upon turning to best account the resources which
the country possesses. But the people have had very little of the necessary spirit of
enterprise in them. The task, therefore, has fallen upon the Government of India to
provide the country with the two prime requisites of a sustained economic life, namely a system of transport and a network of
irrigation. With this object in view the Government had inaugurated a policy of developing
what were called " Extraordinary Public Works,"
financed by capital borrowings. For such borrowings India, as was to be expected, hardly
offered any market, the people being too poor and their savings too scanty to furnish a
modicum of the required capital outlay. Like all governments of poor peoples, the
Government of India had therefore to turn to wealthier countries that had surplus capital
to lend. All these countries unfortunately happened to be on the gold standard. As long as
it was possible to say that so much gold was equal to so much silver, the English investor
was indifferent whether the securities of the Government of India were rupee securities or
sterling securities. But the fall in the gold value of silver was also a fall in the gold
value of the rupee securities, and what was once a secure investment ceased to be so any
more. This placed the Government in a difficult position in
the matter of financing its extraordinary public works. Figures in Table XIII are worth
study.
The English investor would not invest in the
rupee securities. An important customer for the Indian rupee securities was thus lost. The
response of the Indian money market was inadequate.
revenue
and expenditure of THE government oF india
Year. |
Average
Rate of Exchange. |
In
India. |
In
England. |
Final
Result. |
|||
|
|
Net
Revenue. |
Net
Expenditure excluding Exchange. |
Surplus Revenue. |
Net
Sterling Revenue. |
Exchange. |
|
|
R. |
R. |
£ |
R. |
R. |
||
1874-75 |
22.156 |
39,564,216 |
25,897,098 |
13,667,118 |
12,562,101 |
1,045,239 |
59,778 |
1875-76 |
21.626 |
40,053,419 |
24,541,923 |
15,511,496 |
12,544,813 |
1,377,428. |
1,589,255 |
1876-77 |
20.508 |
38,253,366 |
25,355,285 |
12,898,081 |
13,229,646 |
2,252,611 |
-2,584,176 |
1877-78 |
20.791 |
39,275,489 |
27,658,021 |
11,617,468 |
13,756,478 |
2,123,030 |
-4,262,040 |
1878-79 |
19.794 |
44,415,139 |
25,778,928 |
18,636,211 |
13,610,211 |
2,891,902 |
2,134,098 |
1879-80 |
19.961 |
45,258,197 |
29,384,030 |
15,874,167 |
14,223,891 |
2,878,169 |
-1,227,893 |
1880-81 |
19.956 |
44,691,119 |
34,880,434 |
9,810,085 |
11,177,231 |
2,264,848 |
-3,031,394 |
1881-82 |
19.895 |
45,471,887 |
27,717,249 |
17,754,638 |
11,737,688 |
2,421,499 |
3,595,451 |
1882-83 |
19.525 |
42,526,173 |
25,500,437 |
17,025,736 |
13,299,976 |
3,050,923 |
674,837 |
1883-84 |
19.536 |
43,591,273 |
23,566,381 |
20,024,892 |
14,770,257 |
3,375,158 |
1,879,477 |
1884-85 |
19.308 |
41,585,347 |
24,763,779 |
16,821,568 |
13,844,028 |
3,363,986 |
-
386,446 |
1885-86 |
18.254 |
42,635,953 |
27,352,132 |
15,283,821 |
13,755,659 |
4,329,888 |
-2,801,726 |
1886-87 |
17.441 |
44,804,774 |
25,124,335 |
19,680,439 |
14,172,298 |
5,329,714 |
178,427 |
1887-88 |
16.898 |
45,424,150 |
25,968,025 |
19,456,125 |
15,128,018 |
6,356,939 |
-2,028,832 |
1888-89 |
16.379 |
46,558,354 |
25,051,147 |
21,507,207 |
14,652,590 |
6,817,599 |
37,018 |
1889-90 |
16.566 |
50,005,810 |
26,367,855 |
23,637,955 |
14,513,155 |
6,512,767 |
2,612,033 |
1890-91 |
18.090 |
49,403,819 |
25,579,727 |
23,824,092 |
15,176,866 |
4,959,055 |
3,688,171 |
1891-92 |
16.733 |
50,023,142 |
27,013,618 |
23,009,524 |
15,716,780 |
6,825,909 |
467,535 |
To issue sterling securities was the only
alternative to enable the Government to tap a bigger and a more constant reservoir for the
drawing of capital to India; but as it was bound to
increase the burden of the gold payments, which it was the strongest interest of the
Government to reduce, the resort to the London money market, unavoidable as it became, was
somewhat restrained# with the result that the expansion of extraordinary public works did
not proceed at a pace demanded by the needs of the country.
#During
the period of falling exchange the distribution of the debt of India was as follows:
|
Sterling Debt |
Rupee Debt |
End
of 1873-74 |
41,117,617 |
66,41,72,900 |
End
of 1898-99 |
124,268,605 |
1,12,65,04,340 |
Indian
Currency Committee
(1898), Appendix II p. 179
The effects of this financial derangement,
consequent on the fall of the exchange, were not confined to the Government, of India. They were immediately felt by the municipalities
and other local bodies who were dependent upon the Government for financial aid. So long
as the cash balances were overflowing in the treasury of the Government," one of the
most useful ways " to employ them was found in lending
a portion of them to these local institutions. As they had just then been inaugurated
under the local self-government policy of Lord Ripon's
regime, and were looked upon only as an experiment, their taxing and borrowing powers were
rigidly limited. Consequently, this financial aid from the Central Government by way of
temporary advances was a resource of inestimable value to them. When, however, the cash
balances of the Central Government began to diminish owing to the continued losses by
exchange, these facilities were severely curtailed,[f9] so that the very vitality of these
institutions was threatened just at the moment when they needed all help to foster their
growth and strengthen their foundations.
Addressing the Secretary of State, the
Government of India, in a dispatch of February 2, 1886, observed[f10]
" 10. We do
not hesitate to repeat that the facts set forth in the preceding paragraphs are, from the
point of Indian interests, intolerable ; and the evils
which we have enumerated do not exhaust the catalogue. Uncertainty regarding the future of
silver discourages the investment of capital in India, and we find it impossible to borrow
in silver except at an excessive cost.
"On the other hand, the Frontier and
Famine Railways which we propose to construct, and the Coast and Frontier defences which
we have planned, are imperatively required and cannot be postponed indefinitely.
TABLE XIII
price movements oF rupee
aND sterling securities oF THE government oF india [f11]
Year. |
Rates
of Exchange. |
Price
of 4 per cent. Rupee Paper. |
Price
of Sterling India Stock. |
|||||||||
|
|
In
Calcutta. |
In
London. |
4
per cent. |
3
1/2
per cent. |
3
per cent. |
||||||
|
Highest. |
Lowest. |
Highest. |
Lowest. |
Highest. |
Lowest. |
Lowest. |
Highest. |
Lowest. |
Highest. |
||
|
d. |
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
|
1873 |
22
7/8 |
21
5/8 |
105 |
101
7/8 |
97 |
94
½ |
106
½ |
101
¼ |
|
|
|
|
1874 |
23
1/8 |
213 |
104
1/2 |
99
1/2 |
98 |
941 |
103
¾ |
101 |
|
|
|
|
1875 |
22
3/16 |
21
1/4 |
102
7/8 |
101
3/4 |
94 |
91 |
106
¼ |
103
¼ |
|
|
|
|
1876 |
22
3/8 |
18
1/2 |
101
7/8 |
98
3/4 |
89
3/4 |
78 |
105
7/8 |
101
7/8 |
|
|
|
|
1877 |
22
1/4 |
20
9/16 |
981 |
93
1/4 |
88
1/2 |
81 |
104
5/8 |
102
¼ |
|
|
|
|
1878 |
21 |
18 3/4 |
961 |
93
1/2 |
82
1/2 |
751 |
104
5/8 |
99 |
|
|
|
|
1879 |
20
5/8 |
18
5/8 |
941 |
91
1/4 |
80 |
771 |
105
3/8 |
100
7/8 |
|
|
|
|
1880 |
20
3/8 |
19
3/4 |
100 |
92
15/16 |
81
3/8 |
77
3/4 |
105
3/8 |
102
1/8 |
|
|
|
|
1881 |
20
1/16 |
19
1/2 |
104
5/8 |
100 |
86 |
811 |
106
3/8 |
103
7/8 |
103
7/8 |
100
¾ |
|
|
1882 |
20
3/16 |
19
1/16 |
102
1/16 |
95
5/8 |
85 |
81 |
105
1/8 |
102
7/8 |
101
7/8 |
99
¾ |
|
|
1883 |
19
9/16 |
19
3/16 |
101
1/8 |
97
9/16 |
82 |
79
3/4 |
104
5/8 |
102
7/16 |
103
1/8 |
101
3/8 |
|
|
1884 |
19
3/4 |
18
15/16 |
100
5/8 |
95
5/16 |
811 |
78: |
104
3/8 |
101
5/8 |
107
1/8 |
101
3/4 |
96
¼ |
91
3/4 |
1885 |
19
3/16 |
17
3/3 1/2 |
98
7/16 |
921 |
77
1/2 |
731/4 |
103
1/16 |
98
3/4 |
102
¾ |
97
½ |
91
½ |
85
¾ |
1886 |
18 |
16
1/8 |
97
3/4 |
97
3/16 |
73 |
66
¼ |
103
½ |
101
¼ |
102
¾ |
99
¾ |
90
1/8 |
86
5/8 |
1887 |
18
3/16 |
15
5/8 |
99
3/16 |
95
5/16 |
71
11/16 |
67
7/8 |
102
¾ |
100
½ |
103
¼ |
100
1/4 |
92
¾ |
95
3/8 |
1888 |
17
1/8 |
16 |
100
3/16 |
971 |
691 |
66
¼ |
102
7/8 |
100
½ |
107
1/4 |
104
5/8 |
98 |
95 |
1889 |
16
15/16 |
16 |
l00
3/8 |
97
1/16 |
69
1/8 |
66
3/8 |
|
|
109
1/2 |
106
7/8 |
101
1/8 |
99 |
1890 |
20
2/3 9/2 |
16
7/8 |
1031 |
96
13/16 |
87
¼ |
68
3/4 |
|
|
108
1/2 |
105
¼ |
100
¾ |
95
1/4 |
1891 |
18
1/4 |
16
5/8 |
107
13/16 |
104
1/16 |
80
¾ |
74
½ |
|
|
109
1/2 |
105 |
99 |
94
7/8 |
1892 |
16
11/16 |
14
5/8 |
108
15/16 |
103
11/16 |
74
1/2 |
62 |
|
|
109
½ |
106
1/8 |
98
½ |
94
7/8 |
"We are forced, therefore, either to
increase our sterling liabilities, to which course there are so many objections, or to do
without the railways required for the commercial development of the country, and its
protection against invasion and the effects of famine.
***
" 11. Nor can the difficulties which local bodies experience in
borrowing in India be overlooked. The Municipalities of Bombay and Calcutta require large
sums for sanitary improvements, but the high rate of interest which they must pay for
silver loans operates to deter them from undertaking expensive works, and we need hardly
remind your Lordship that it has quite recently been found necessary for Government to
undertake to lend the money required for the construction of docks at Calcutta and Bombay,
and that when the Port Commissioners of Calcutta attempted to raise a loan of 75 lakhs of
rupees in September, 1885, guaranteed by the Government of India, the total amount of
tenders was only Rs. 40,200, and no portion of this
insignificant amount was offered at par........."
The importation of capital on private account
was hampered for similar reasons, to the great detriment of
the country. It was urged on all hands, and was even recommended by a Royal Commission, [f12]that one avenue of escape from the ravages of recurring
famines, to which India so pitifully succumbed at such frequent intervals, was the
diversification of her industries. To be of any permanent benefit, such diversified
industrial life could be based on a capitalistic basis alone. But that depended upon the
flow of capital into the country as freely as the needs of the country required. As
matters then stood, the English investor, the largest purveyor of capital, looked upon the
investment of capital in India as a risky proposition. It was feared that once the capital
was spread out in a silver country every fall in the price of silver would not only make
the return uncertain when drawn in gold, but would also reduce the capital value of his
investment in terms of gold, which was naturally the unit in which he measured all his
returns and his outlays. This check to the free inflow of
capital was undoubtedly the most serious evil arising out of the rupture of the par of
exchange.
Another group of people, who suffered from the
fall of exchange because of their obligation to make gold payments, was composed of the
European members of the Civil Service in India. Like the Government to which they
belonged, they received their salaries in silver, but had to make gold remittances in
support of their families, who were often left behind in England. Before 1873, when the
price of silver in terms of gold was fixed, this circumstance was of no moment to them.
But as the rupee began to fall the face of the situation was completely altered. With
every fall in the value of silver they had to pay more rupees out of their fixed salaries
to obtain the same amount of gold. Some relief was no doubt given to them in the matter of
their remittances. The Civil Servants were permitted, at a sacrifice to the Government, to
make their remittances at what was called the Official Rate of Exchange.[f13] It is true the difference between the market rate and
the official rate was not very considerable. None the less, it was appreciable enough for
the Civil Servants to have gained by 2 1/2 per cent. on the average of the years 1862-90[f14] at the cost of the Government. The Military
Servants obtained a similar relief to a greater degree, but in a different way. Their
salary was fixed in sterling, though payable in rupees. It is true the Royal Warrant which
fixed their salary also fixed the rate of exchange between the sterling and the rupee for
that purpose. But as it invariably happened that the rate of exchange fixed by the Warrant
was higher than the market rate, the Military Servants were compensated to the extent of
the difference at the cost of the Indian Exchequer##.
##Cf.
F. S. 1887-8, pp. 39-40.
This
cost was as follows
1847
75 |
Rs.
6,40,000 |
1885
86 |
Rs.
4,00,000 |
1884
85 |
Rs.
18,43,000
|
1886
-87 |
Rs.
5,15,000 |
This relief was, comparatively speaking, no
relief to them. The official or the warrant rates of exchange, though better than the
market rates of exchange, were much lower than the rate at which they were used to make
their remittances before 1873. Their burden, like that of the Government, grew with the
fall of silver, and as their burden increased their attitude became alarmist. Many were
the memorialists who demanded from the Government adequate compensation for their losses
on exchange.[f15] The Government was warned[f16]that
"the ignorant folk who think India would
be benefited by lowering present salaries are seemingly unable to comprehend that such a
step would render existence on this reduced pay simply impossible, and that recourse would
of necessity be had to other methods of raising money."
Such, no doubt, was the case in the earlier
days of the East India Company, when the Civil Servants fattened on pickings because their
pay was small,[f17] and it was to put a stop to their
extortions that their salaries were raised to what appears an extra-ordinary level.
That such former instances of extortions should have been held out as monitions
showed too well how discontented the Civil Service was owing to its losses through
exchange.
Quite a different effect the fall had on the
trade and industry of the country. It was in a flourishing state as compared with the
affairs of the Government or with the trade and industry of a gold-standard country like
England. Throughout the period of falling silver there was said to be a progressive
decline relatively to population in the employment afforded by various trades and
industries in England. The textile manufactures and the iron and coal trade were depressed
as well as the other important trades, including the hardware manufactures of Birmingham
and Sheffield, the sugar-refining of Greenock, Liverpool,
and London, the manufactures of earthenware, glass, leather, paper, and a multitude of
minor industries.
[f18]The depression in English agriculture was so widespread that
the Commissioners of 1892 were " unable to point to
any part of the country in which [the effects of the depression] can be said to be
entirely absent," and this notwithstanding the fact that the seasons since 1882
"were on the whole satisfactory from an agricultural point of view."[f19] Just the reverse was the case with Indian
trade and industry. The foreign trade of the country, which had bounced
up during the American Civil War, showed greater buoyancy after 1870, and continued to
grow throughout the period of the falling exchange at a rapid pace. During the short space
of twenty years the total imports and exports of the country more than doubled in their
magnitude, as is shown by Table XIV.
TABLE XIV
imports aND exports
(BOTH merchandize aND treasure)[f20]
Year |
Exports |
Imports |
Year |
Exports |
Imports |
|
|
|
R. |
|
|
1870-71 |
57,556,951 |
39,913,942 |
1881-82 |
83,068,198 |
60,436,155 |
1871-72 |
64,685,376 |
43,665,663 |
1882-83 |
84,527,182 |
65,548,868 |
1872-73 |
56,548,842 |
36,431,210 |
1883-84 |
89,186,397 |
68,157,311 |
1873-74 |
56,910,081 |
39,612,362 |
1884-85 |
85,225,922 |
69,591,269 |
1874-75 |
57,984,549 |
44,363,160 |
1885-86 |
84,989,502 |
71,133,666 |
1875-76 |
60,291,731 |
44,192,378 |
1886-87 |
90,190,633 |
72,830,670 |
1876-87 |
65,043,789 |
48,876,751 |
1887-88 |
92,148,279 |
78,830,468 |
1877-78 |
67,433,324 |
58,819,644 |
1888-89 |
98,833,879 |
83,285,427 |
1878-79 |
64,919,741 |
44,857,343 |
1889-90 |
105,366,720 |
86,656,990 |
1879-80 |
69,247,511 |
52,821,398 |
1890-91 |
102,350,526 |
93,909,856 |
1880-81 |
76,021,043 |
62,104,984 |
1891-92 |
111,460,278 |
84,155,045 |
TABLE XV.
nature of industrial PURSUITS in england and india [f21]
|
||||||||||
|
Manufactured
Articles. |
Raw
Materials. |
Food
Articles |
Unclassified
Articles. |
Total. |
Manufactured
Articles. |
Raw
Materials. |
Food
Articles |
Unclassified
Articles. |
Total. |
1857 |
11 |
34 |
22 |
23 |
100 |
90.9 |
4 |
4.9 |
.2 |
100 |
1858 |
6 |
35 |
26 |
33 |
100 |
91.4 |
3.4 |
5.1 |
.1 |
100 |
1859 |
6.5 |
40 |
15.5 |
38 |
100 |
91.5 |
3.8 |
4.6 |
.1 |
100 |
1860 |
5.7 |
43.6 |
17.7 |
33 |
100 |
91.9 |
3.6 |
4.4 |
.3 |
100 |
1861 |
5.8 |
46.5 |
15.3 |
32.4 |
100 |
90.4 |
4.8 |
4.8 |
|
100 |
1862 |
5 |
52 |
16 |
27 |
100 |
90.3 |
4 |
4.8 |
.9 |
100 |
1863 |
3.7 |
58.7 |
10.6 |
27 |
100 |
91.0 |
4 |
4 |
1.0 |
100 |
1864 |
4 |
69.2 |
9.3 |
17.5 |
100 |
92.5 |
3.7 |
3.7 |
.1 |
100 |
1865 |
3.5 |
68 |
12 |
16.6 |
100 |
92.1 |
3.6 |
3.6 |
.7 |
100 |
1866 |
4.2 |
67.2 |
10.3 |
18.3 |
100 |
92 |
3.7 |
3.7 |
.4 |
100 |
1867 |
4 |
58 |
11 |
27 |
100 |
92.2 |
3.8 |
3.7 |
.3 |
100 |
1868 |
4 |
58-5 |
11.5 |
26 |
100 |
92 |
4.4 |
3.4 |
.2 |
100 |
1869 |
4.8 |
60.5 |
14 |
20.7 |
100 |
92 |
4.2 |
3.1 |
.7 |
100 |
1870 |
4.4 |
63.6 |
9 |
23 |
100 |
91 |
4 |
4 |
1.0 |
100 |
1871 |
3.7 |
65.3 |
11 |
20 |
100 |
90 |
4-4 |
4.9 |
.'7 |
100 |
1872 |
3-3 |
61.4 |
13.5 |
21.8 |
100 |
91.2 |
5.4 |
3.5 |
.9 |
100 |
TABLE XVI
changes IN industrial
pursuits oF india[f22]
|
Imports |
Exports |
||
Years |
Manufactured |
Raw |
Manufactured |
Raw |
|
Rs. |
Rs. |
Rs. |
|
1879 |
25,98,65,827 |
13,75,55,837 |
5,27,80,340 |
59,67,27,991 |
1892 |
36,22,31,872 |
26,38,18,431 |
16,42,47,566 |
85,52,09,499 |
Percentage of increase |
39 |
91 |
211 |
43 |
Total Annual |
2.8 |
6.5 |
15 |
3 |
Not only had the trade of India been
increasing, but the nature of her industries was also at the same time undergoing a profound change. Prior to 1870, India and England
were, so to say, non-competing groups. Owing to the protectionist policy of the Navigation
Laws, and owing also to the substitution of man by machinery in the field of production,
India had become exclusively an agricultural and a raw-material-producing country, while
England had transformed herself into a country which devoted all her energy and her
resources to the manufacturing of raw materials imported from abroad into finished goods.
How marked was the contrast in the industrial pursuits in the two countries is well
revealed by the analysis of their respective exports in Table XV.
After 1870, the distribution of their
industrial pursuits was greatly altered, and India once again began to assume the role of
a manufacturing country. Analyzing the figures for Indian imports and exports for the
twenty years succeeding 1870, (see Table XVI)
we find that the progress in the direction of manufactures formed one of the most
significant features of the period.
This change in the industrial evolution was
marked by the growth of two principal manufactures. One of them was the manufacture of
cotton. The cotton industry was one of the oldest industries of India, but during 100
years between 1750 and 1850 it had failed into a complete
state of decrepitude. Attempts were made to resuscitate the industry on a capitalistic
basis in the sixties of the nineteenth century and soon showed signs of rapid advance. The
story of its progress is graphically illustrated in the following summary in Table XVII :
TABLE XVII
THE DEVELOPMENT OF INDIA COTTON TRADE AND
INDUSTRY
|
Growth of Trade (Average
Annual Quantities |
||||
|
in each Quinquennium) |
||||
|
1870-71 |
1875-76 |
1880-81 |
1885-86 |
1890-91 |
|
to |
to |
to |
to |
to |
|
1874-75 |
1879-80 |
1884-85 |
1889-90 |
1894-95 |
Imports of raw
cottonthousands of cwts. |
23 |
52 |
51 |
74 |
89 |
Imports of raw
cottonthousands of cwts. |
5236 |
3988 |
5477 |
5330 |
4660 |
Imports of twist and yarn |
33.55 |
33.55 |
44.34 |
49.09 |
44.79 |
|
Growth of Industry (at end of
each fifth year) |
||||
Number of mills |
48 |
58 |
81 |
114 |
143 |
Number of
spindles000omitted |
1,000 |
1,471 |
2,037 |
2,935 |
3,712 |
Number of
looms000omitted |
10 |
13 |
16 |
22 |
34 |
Number of persons employed |
|
39,537 |
61,836 |
99,224 |
|
Another industry which
figured largely in this expansion of Indian manufactures was jute. Unlike the cotton
industry of India, the jute industry was of a comparatively recent origin. Its growth,
different from that of the cotton industry, was fostered by the application of European
capital, European management, and European skill, and it soon took as deep roots as the
cotton industry and flourished as well as the latter did, if not better. Its history was
one of continued progress as will be seen from Table XVIII.
This increasing trend towards manufactures was
not without its indirect effects on the course of Indian agriculture. Prior to 1870 the
Indian farmer, it may be said, had no commercial outlook. He cultivated not so much for
profit as for individual self-sufficiency. After 1870 farming tended to become a business
and crops came more and more to be determined by the course of market prices than by the
household needs of the farmer. This is well illustrated by figures in Table XIX.
Such was the contrast in
the economic conditions prevalent in the two countries. This peculiar phenomenon of a
silver-standard country steadily progressing, and a gold-standard country tending to a
standstill, exercised the minds of many of its observers.
[f1]
Since the Reform Act of 1920 that part of this cost which was " political " has
been placed upon the British Estimates.
[f2]
Compiled from figures in Appendix II, p. 270 of the Indian Currency Committee of 1843
[f3]Report of the
Indian Currency Committee, 1893, App. II,
p. 263.
[f4]
J.E.O'Conor, Report of the Indian Currency
Committee, 1898, App. II, p. 182
[f5]
Cf. Report of the Public Service Commission, C.
5327 of 1887.
[f6]
This provision of the Act has been re-enacted by the Act of 1861
[f7]Cf.
evidence of Mr. Jenkins, Q. 12. Mit. of Evid. of the Select Committee on East India (Civil
Servants), H. of C. 327 of 1890
[f8]
Cf. Calcutta Civil Finance Committee's Report,
1886 ; also The Report of the Civil Finance Commissioner
(1887), who completed the work of the Committee after it was dissolved.
[f9]
Cf. Financial Statement, 1876-77, p. 94.
[f10]
Cf. Financial Statement, 1876-77, p. 94. * See C. 4868 of 1886, p. 8.
[f11]
Appendix II to the Report of the Indian Currency
Committee of 1893, p. 272. These prices differ slightly from those given in Appendix
IV to the First Report of the Gold and Silver Commission, 1886 , and also from those in the Statistics of division called Prices
British India (First Issue) for 1906-07, Part IV, (a) Finance Tables 7 and 8 of the
[f12]Cf.
The Report of the Famine Commission of 1880,
Part II, C. 2735 of 1880 pp.
175-76.
[f13]
As was explained by Mr. Waterfield before the Select Committee on East India (Civil
Servants), H. C. Return 327 of 1890, Q. 1905-17, it was first instituted in 1824 and was
arrived at as follows : In December of each year a calculation was made at the India
Office of the cost of sending a rupee to India, based on the market price of silver in
London, and of the cost of bringing a rupee from India, based on the price of bills on
London in Calcutta. A mean between the two was struck and taken as the adjusting rate for
the coming official year between the India Office and the British Treasury in regard to
such transactions or payments undertaken by one Government as the agent of the other. It
was fixed anew for each and formed a fair average rate, although it was sometimes above
and sometimes below the market rate of exchange.
[f14]
Ibid., Q. 1925-26
[f15]
Cf. Report of the Indian Currency Committee,
1893, App. I, pp. 185-90 and p. 202, for memorials of the European Civil Servants.
[f16]
Cf. Col. Hughes-Hallett.M.P., The Depreciation of
the Rupee : its Effect on the Anglo-Indian Officialthe Wrong and the Remedy,
London, 1887, p. 14.
[f17]
The connection between the rapacious conduct of the early European Civil Servants and the
smallness of their salaries was well brought out by Clive in his speech dated March 30,
1772, during the course of the debate in the House of Commons on the East India Judicature
Bill, Hansard. Vol. XVII, pp. 334-39.
[f18]
Report by Dunraven, Farrer, Muntz, and Lubbock in the Final Report of the Royal Commission on Depression of
Trade and Industry, par., 54, C. 4893.
[f19]
Final Report of the Royal Commission on Agricultural Depression in England, C. 8540 of
1897, par. 28.
[f21]
The figures for India are calculated from the Statistical
Abstract for British India, Second Number (1857-1866), Table No. 34, and the Eighth
Number (1864-1873), Table No. 24. Figures for England are taken from Appendix C (Statement
6) to the First Report of the Royal Commission of
the Depression of Trade and Industry, 1885, with this alterationthat the
separate figures in the original under ' ' Manufactured ' ' and ' ' Partially Manufactured
' ' are here grouped under ' ' Manufactured." 'The "Unclassified Articles "
under Indian Exports are for the most part "Jewellery
[f22]
From Ranade's Essays on Indian Economics, p.
104.