________________________________________________________________________________________
CHAPTER V
FROM A GOLD STANDARD TO A GOLD EXCHANGE STANDARD
For once it seemed that the problem of a depreciating rupee was satisfactorily solved. The anxieties and difficulties that extended over a long period of a quarter of a century could not but have been fully compensated by the adoption of a remedy like the one described in the last chapter. But by an unkind turn of events, the system originally contemplated failed to come into being. In its place there grew up a system of currency in India which was in every way the very reverse of it. Some thirteen years after legislative sanction had been given to the recommendations of the Fowler Committee, the Chamberlain Commission on Indian Finance and Currency reported that
" in spite of the fact the Government adopted
and intended to carry out the recommendations of the Committee of 1898, the Indian
currency system to-day differs considerably from that contemplated by the Committee,
whilst the mechanism for maintaining the exchange has some important features in common
with the suggestions made to the Committee by Mr. A. M. Lindsay."[f1]
It will be recalled[f2] that in Mr. Lindsay's
scheme Indian currency was to be entirely a rupee currency; the Government was to give
rupees in every case in return for gold, and gold for rupees only in case of foreign
remittances. The scheme was to be worked through the instrumentality of two offices, one
located in London and the other located in India, the former to sell drafts on the latter
when rupees were wanted and the latter to sell drafts on the former when gold was wanted.
Surprisingly similar is the system prevailing in India to-day. Corresponding to Mr.
Lindsay's proposals, which, be it noted, were rejected in 1898, the Government of India
has built up two reserves, one of gold and the other of rupees, out of the cash balances,
the paper currency, and the gold-standard reserve. Each of these is, by the nature of the
currency system, composite. The cash balances, which are fed
from revenue receipts, gather in their net rupees as well as sovereigns, both being legal
tender. Notes being issuable against both, the
paper-currency reserve always contains sovereigns and
rupees. Up to August, 1915, the gold-standard reserve was also held partly in gold and partly in rupees.[f3]
By a system of sorting, technically
called "
transfers," the Government secures the command over rupees and sovereigns necessary
for discharging the obligations it has undertaken.[f4] The location of these funds is also very much as designed by Mr. Lindsay. The cash balances, being
the till-money of the Government, are necessarily
distributed between the Government of India in India and
the Secretary of State in London, the portion held by the latter being entirely in gold
and that held by the former being in silver. The gold-standard reserve, like the cash balances, is not a statutory reserve. Consequently its location
is perfectly within the competence of the Executive. That
being so, it has been so arranged that the gold portion of
the fund shall be held by
the Secretary of State in London, and the rupee portion, so long as it was maintained, by
the Government of India in India. The only reserve which did not easily lend itself to currency manipulation
was the paper-currency reserve, for the reason that its disposition and location were
governed by law. In that behalf, legal power has been taken
to alter the location of the gold part of that reserve by
making permanent the provision of the temporary Act II of 1896, which authorised the issue
of notes in India against gold tendered to the Secretary of
State in London. Thus the Secretary of State and the Government of india, under the new system of currency, hold two reserves,
one of gold, mainly in the possession of the former and located in London, and the other of rupees, entirely in the
possession of the latter and held
in India. But the similarity of the existing system to that of Mr. Lindsay is not confined to the maintenance of these funds and
their location. It extends even to the modes of operating
these two funds, For, as
suggested by Mr. Lindsay, when rupees are wanted in India the Secretary of State sells what are called "Council Bills," encashable into rupees at the Government Treasuries in India,
thereby providing the rupee currency in India. When gold is wanted the Government of India sells what are called "
Reverse Councils " on the home Treasury in London,
which are encashed by the Secretary of State, thereby providing gold for foreign
remittances. The result of the sale of " Council Bills " and of the "
Reverse Councils " on the two funds has been to
transform the Indian currency from being a gold standard with a gold currency, as desired
by the Fowler Committee, into what is called a gold standard without a
gold currency, as wished for by Mr. Lindsay.
This system which has grown up in place of the
system originally contemplated by the Government of india
is called the gold-exchange standard. Whatever that
designation may mean it was not the plan originally contemplated by the Government of
India in 1398. How the departure came about we shall deal
with in another place. Here it is enough to state-one may also say necessary, for
many writers seem to have fallen into an error on this
pointthat the Government
did not start to establish a gold-exchange standard. Rather it was contemplating the
establishing of a true gold standard, which, however
inadequately understood by the men who framed it, was in essential agreement with the
principles governing the English
Bank Charter Act of 1844.
What are we to say about the new system ? The Chamberlain Commission, while
reporting that there was a departure from the idea! of a gold standard with a gold
currency, observed[f5] :
" But to
state there has been this departure is by no means to condemn the action taken, or the
system actually in force......"
Now why not ? Is
not the system the same as that proposed by the Government in India in 1878 and condemned
by the Committee of 1879 ? it is true the arguments urged
against that plan by the Committee of 1879 were not of much
weight.[f6] Nonetheless the plan was essentially unsound.
The material point in the introduction of a gold standard
must be said to be one of limitation on the volume of
rupees, and it is from this point of view that we must judge the plan. But there was
nothing in the plan of 1878 that could be said to have been
calculated to bring that about. Far from putting any
limitation on the volume of rupees, the plan had
deliberately left the Mints open to the free coinage of silver. A matter of some interest
in the plan was the projection of a system of seignorage so
arranged so to make the bullion value of the rupee equal to the gold value given to it.
But as a means of limiting the coinage of rupees it was futile. The mere levy of a
seignorage cannot be regarded as sufficient in all circumstances to effect a limitation of
coinage. Everything would have depended upon how closely
the seignorage corresponded with the difference between the mint and market price of
silver in terms of gold. If the seignorage fell short of the difference it would have
given a direct impetus to increased coinage of rupees until their redundancy had driven
them to a discount. In this respect the plan was a reproduction in a worse form of the
English Gold Standard Act of 1816. Like the Government of India's plan of 1878, that Act,
while purporting to introduce a gold standard, had authorised the opening of the Mint,
which was closed, to the free coinage of silver with a seignorage charge. It is not
generally recognised how stupid were the provisions of that Act,[f7] the ideal of all orthodox gold monometallists, in so far as they contemplated the free
coinage of silver. Fortunately for England the Royal Proclamation, compelling the Mint Master to coin all silver
brought to the mint, was never issued. Otherwise the working of the gold standard would have been considerably jeopardized.[f8] The Act of 1816 had at least taken one
precaution, and that was a limit on the legal-tender power
of silver. In the scheme of the Government of India, not only free coinage of silver was
permitted, but silver was conceded the right of full legal tender. In so far, therefore,
as the plan did not provide for controlling the volume of rupees it was subversive of the
gold standard it had in view.
The only difference between this plan of 1878
and the system now in operation in India is that under the former the Mints were open to
the public, while under the latter they are open to the Government alone. In other words,
in the one case rupees were coined on behalf of the public,
and in the other they are being coined on behalf of the Government. It is not to be
supposed that the plan of closing the Mints to the public was not thought of by the
Government in 1878. On the other hand, the Government of India had then considered the
feasibility of taking over into its hands the coinage of rupees, and had rejected it on
some very excellent grounds. In their dispatch outlining the scheme the Government of the
day observed:
"48. The first point to be guarded in
attempting to carry out the proposed change, is to provide for complete freedom for any
expansion of the currency which the trade requirements of the country demand. This, we
think could not be properly secured if the Mints were wholly closed for the coining of
silver for the public. If this measure were adopted, the responsibility for supplying the
silver demand would be thrown on the Government, and in the present position of the market
for gold and silver bullion in India it would not be possible
to accept such a duty.
"49. What might at first sight appear the
simplest, and therefore the best way of allowing for the expansion of the Indian silver
currency with a gold standard, would be for the Government to undertake to give silver
coin in exchange for gold coin to all comers, at the rates fixed by the new system, and to
open the Mints for the coinage of gold, while they were closed for silver. But in the
absence of any supply of silver in india from which to
obtain the necessary material for coinage, such an obligation could not be accepted,
without involving the Government in complicated transactions in the purchase and storing
of bullion which it would be very inexpedient to enter on."
With these reasons, interesting in so far as
they were prophetic of the scandals connected with the recent silver purchases by the
India Office, [f9]we are not directly concerned. What is of importance is
whether this difference in the mode of issue makes any vital difference to the question of
an effective limit on the volume of rupees. Now, there is a great deal of confused
thinking as to the precise virtue of the closing of the Mints to the private coinage of
silver. It was generally believed, the closing of the Mints having given a monopoly to the
Government in the matter of issuing rupees, that this monopoly would somehow sustain the
value of the rupees in terms of gold by preventing their over-issue. The closing of the
Mints, it must be admitted, has given the Government the position of a monopolist. But how
a monopoly prevents an over-issue is not easy to grasp. The closing of the Mints to the
free coinage of silver is the same as depriving banks of the liberty of issuing notes and
giving it exclusively to a central bank. But nobody has ever argued that because a central
bank has a monopoly of issue it cannot therefore over-issue. Similarly, because the
Government of India is a monopolist it would be absurd to argue that it cannot therefore
over-issue. Indeed, a monopolist can issue as much as private people put together, if not
more. Again, from the standpoint of influence of profits on coinage the present plan is
much inferior to that of 1878. It is true in both cases profits depend upon the volume of
coinage. But in the former the amount of profit was no incentive to coinage, either to the
Government, because it had no power to coin, or to the people who determined the volume of
coinage, because the regulation of seignorage practically controlled it by making it unprofitable to bring additional
bullion to the Mint. In the present case, the coinage being entirely in the hands of the
Government, a hankering after profits, generated by the silly notion of the necessity of a
" backing " to the
currency, might create an impulse to undertake additional coinage,
especially if the price of silver fell very low and produced a wide margin between the
Mint and the market price of the rupee.[f10]
If it is argued, as it well may be, that the
will of the Government of India as a monopolist, i.e. its desire to see that its currency
is not depreciated, may bring about a limitation on the
issue of rupees which could not have been possible had the Mints remained open to the
public in general, the reply is that this will to limit could be effective only if the
Government had the power to refuse to issue. Central banks limit their currencies so far
as will is concerned, because they are not obligated to issue to anyone and everyone. But
the position of the Government of India is lamentably weak
in this respect. It is bound to issue currency when asked for. It
is true that every issue does not involve a net addition to the existing volume of
currency; for a portion of the new issue is a re-issue of what is returned from
circulation. Nonetheless, it
cannot be said that the Government by reason of its monopoly has put an effective limit on
the volume of rupee currency. On the other hand, having no escape from the liability to issue currency, the exercise of this cherished privilege has recoiled on the Government, so much so that this
monopoly of issue, instead of strengthening the position of
the Government, has weakened it considerably.[f11] The
view of the Chamberlain Commission.[f12]
" that while the Government are very large dealers in the exchange market, they are not
monopolists (!) and it seems doubtful if they could
successfully stand out for any such [fixed minimum rate] at
all times of the year,"
is therefore
interesting as a confession that the closing of the Mints
has not had the virtue of so limiting the coinage of rupees as to enable the Government to dictate at ail times the price of the rupee,
which none but it alone can manufacture.
Thus the present standard is different from the
standard proposed in 1878 only in name. If this one is
characterised by the adoption of the rate of exchange as an index for regulating the volume of currency, the same must be said of the former. But as Mr. Hawtrey remarks,[f13] whatever means are adopted for the
manipulation of the currency,
" the value of the rupee will be determined by the quantity in
circulation."
in other words, what must be said to be
essential for the safety of a gold standard is a provision
against over-issue of rupees. But, as we saw, neither the plan
of 1878 nor the present one can be said to be free from that danger. Consequently we must
conclude that, being essentially alike, the arguments that are valid against the former are also valid against the latter.
But the Chamberlain Commission will not allow that the exchange standard is a resuscitation of a condemned plan.
On the other hand, it has sought to inspire confidence in
that standard by holding out[f14]
"that the present Indian system has close affinities with other currency systems in some of the
great European countries and elsewhere......"
To get an idea as to what these affinities are,
or rather were, we must look into Chapter II of Mr. Keynes's
interesting treatise on Indian Currency and Finance.
In that treatise of his, Mr. Keynes has attempted to show
that there is a fundamental likeness between the operations of the Indian currency system
and the operations as they used to be of the central banks of some of the important
countries of Europe. He found that it used to be the practice of these banks to hold
foreign bills of exchange for the purpose of making remittances to foreign countries.
Between the selling of such foreign bills and selling of
reverse councils by the Government of India he observed a close
fundamental likeness, inasmuch as both involved
" the use of a local currency mainly not of gold, some
degree of unwillingness to supply gold locally in exchange for the local currency, but a high degree of willingness to sell foreign
exchange for payment in local currency at a certain maximum rate."[f15]
But, as Prof. Kemmerer
points out,[f16] it is difficult
to see what likeness there is between the Government of India selling reverse councils and
the European banks holding foreign bills. Far from being
alike, the two practices must be regarded as the opposite of each other. In selling reverse councils
"the Government sells drafts against its
foreign gold credit (i.e. its gold reserve), when money at home
is relatively redundant, as evidenced by exchange having reached the gold export point.
Thereby it relieves the redundancy through the withdrawing from circulation and locking up the local money
received in payment for the drafts. Under the practice of holding foreign bills to protect the money market, the central bank sells its
foreign bills, when money at home is relatively scarce, as means of securing gold for importation or preventing its exportation. In the
former case, the sale of drafts takes the place of an
exportation of gold, and the resulting withdrawal of local money from circulation is in essentials an exportation ; in the
latter case the sale of the drafts abroad is part of a process for securing gold for
importation, or for preventing its exportation."
The Indian currency system therefore bears no
analogy to the European currency systems, as Mr. Keynes would have us believe. But if a
parallel is needed, then the true parallel to the Indian
system of currency is that system which prevailed in England during the Bank Suspension
period (1797-1821). The fundamental likeness between the two systems becomes quite
unmistakable if we keep aside for the moment the remittance operations of the Government
of India and the Secretary of State, which becloud the true features of the Indian
currency system. If we tear this veil and take a close view, the following appear to be
the prominent features of the Indian system :
(1) The gold sovereign is full legal tender.
(2) The silver rupee is also full legal tender.
(3) The Government undertakes to give rupees
for sovereigns, but does not undertake to give sovereigns for rupees, i.e. the rupee is an
inconvertible currency unlimited in issue.
Turning to the English system of currency
during the period of the Bank Suspension, we find:
(1) The gold sovereign was full legal tender.
(2) The paper notes of the Bank of England
circulated as money of general acceptability by common custom if not by law.[f17]
(3) The Bank of England undertook to give notes
for gold or mercantile bills or any other kind of good equivalent, but did not give gold
for notes, i.e. the notes formed an inconvertible currency
unlimited in issue.
Only in one respect can the analogy be said to
be imperfect. The Indian Government has undertakennot, be it noted, as a statutory
obligation, but merely as a matter subject to the will of the executive, to convert the
rupee into gold at a fixed rate for foreign remittances if the exchange falls below par.
This, it must be allowed, the bank of England did not do during the suspension period.
Everything, therefore, turns upon the question whether this much convertibility is a
sufficient distinction to mark off the Indian currency from the English currency of the
suspension period into a separate category and invalidate the analogy herein said to exist
between the two systems. To be able to decide one way or the other we must firmly grasp
what is the true import of convertibility. Prejudice against an inconvertible currency is
so strong that people are easily satisfied with a system
which provides some kind of convertibility, however small. But to assume this attitude is
to trifle with a very crucial question. We must keep dear in our mind what it is that
essentially marks off a convertible from an inconvertible currency.
The distinction commonly drawn, that the one is an automatic and the other is a managed
currency, must be discarded as a gross error. For, if by a managed currency we mean a
currency the issue of which depends upon the discretion of the issuer, then a convertible currency is as much a managed currency as an inconvertible
currency is. The only point of contrast lies in the fact that in the management of a convertible
currency the discretion as to issue is regulated, while in
an inconvertible currency it is unregulated. But even if
regulated the issue remains discretionary and to that extent a convertible currency is not
so safe as to mark it off from an inconvertible currency. The enlargement of its issue
being discretionary and the effect of such issues being to drive specie out of
circulation, a convertible currency may easily become inconvertible. The difference
between a convertible and an inconvertible currency is
therefore ultimately a distinction between a prudent and an
imprudent management of the right to issue currency. In other words, convertibility is a
brake on the power of issue. Bearing this in mind, and also the fact that a convertible currency by reason of
mismanagement has the tendency to become inconvertible, it is possible for us to imagine how severe must be the obligations as to
convertibility in order to prevent prudent management of currency from degenerating into
an imprudent management resulting in over-issue. If, therefore, it is true that in
countries having a convertible currency the affairs were so
prudently managed that when specie left the country the paper money not only did not
increase to take its place, but actually diminished, and
that usually by a greater absolute amount than the gold currency, it was because the obligations as to convertibility
were those of "
effective absolute immediate convertibility."[f18] We can now appreciate why Prof. Sumner said[f19] that
"convertibility in the currency is like
conscientiousness in a man : it has many grades and is
valuable in proportion as it is strict and pure."
That being so, it would be foolish to assume
that we are immune from the consequences of an inconvertible currency until we know what
is the grade of the convertibility that is provided. Now, what is the character of the
convertibility of the rupee in India ? It is a deferred,
delegalised, delocalised,
and therefore a devitalised kind of convertibility. Indeed,
really speaking it is not a convertibility, but rather it is a moratorium which is a
negation of convertibility, for what does the provision for convertibility for foreign
remittances mean in practice ? It simply means that until a fall of exchange takes place there is a
moratorium or inconvertibility in respect of the rupee. Not only
is there a moratorium as long as exchange does not fall, but there is no guarantee that
the moratorium will be lifted when a fall does occur. it
may not be lifted, for it is a matter of conscience and not of law.[f20] Is such a grade of convertibility, if one has
a predilection for that term, very far removed from the inconvertibility of the bank notes
during the suspension period ? Let those who will say so.
For a person not endowed with high and subtle imagination
the distinction between such a convertibility and absolute inconvertibility is too thin to
persuade him that the two systems are radically different;
indeed, when we come to analyse the problem of prices in India and outside India we shall
find another piece of evidence to show that they are not different, and that the analogy
between the two is perfect enough for all practical
purposes.
It may, however, he said that an inconvertible
currency may be so well managed as not to give rise to a premium on gold, so that there
may be little to choose between it and a perfectly convertible currency. But whether an
inconvertible currency will be so well managed is a question of practical working. Again,
whether the absence of premium on gold suffices to place an inconvertible currency on par
with a convertible currency, so far as the price problem is concerned, is also a matter
depending on circumstances. Ail these questions will be
considered in their proper places.[f21] What we are considering at this stage are the
inherent potentialities of an inconvertible currency. Suffice it to say here that the name
Gold Exchange Standard cannot conceal the true nature of the Indian Monetary Standard. Its
essence consists in the fact that although gold is unlimited legal tender there is alongside an unlimited issue of another form of fiduciary
currency well-nigh inconvertible, and also possessing the quality
of unlimited legal tender.
It needs no acute power of penetration to see
that, so interpreted, the existing currency system in India is the opposite of the system
outlined by the Government in 1898 and passed by the Fowler Committee. The two are
opposites of each other for the same reason for which the Bank Charter Act was the
opposite of the Bank Suspension Act in England. Under both the Acts the currency in
England was a mixed currency, partly gold and partly paper. The difference was that by the
Bank Suspension Act the issue of gold became limited and that of paper unlimited, while under the Bank Charter Act the process was
reversed, so that the issue of paper became limited and that of gold unlimited. In the
same manner, under the original scheme of the Government of India, the issue of rupees was
to be limited and that of gold unlimited. Under the existing system the issue of gold has
become limited while that of rupee has become unlimited.
Was this an improvement on
the plan originally contemplated by the Government of India ?
The only objection to that plan was that it made the rupee an inconvertible rupee.[f22] But is convertibility
such a necessary condition, and, if so, when ? The idea
that convertibility is necessary to maintain the value of a currency is, on the face of
it, a preposterous idea. No one wants the conversion of bananas into apples to maintain
the value of bananas. Bananas maintain their value by reason of the fact that there is a
demand for them and their supply is limited. There is no reason to suppose that currency
forms an exception to this rule. Only we are more concerned to maintain the value of
currency at a stable level than we are of bananas because currency forms a common measure
of value. What is wanted to maintain the value of currency, or of any other thing for the
matter of that, is an effective limit on its supply. Convertibility is useful, not because
it directly maintains the value of a currency, which is nonsense, but because it has the
effect of putting a limit on the supply of currency. But convertibility is not the only
way of achieving that object. A plan which lays down an absolute limit on issue has the same
effectindeed, a far more powerful effecton the supply of currency. Now, had
the Mints remained entirely closed to the coinage of rupees there would have been placed
an absolute limit on the issue of currency, and all the purposes of convertibility would have been served by
such an inconvertible rupee. Nay, more ; such an
inconvertible rupee currency would have been infinitely
superior to the kind of pseudo-convertible rupee which we have in India to-day.[f23] With an absolute limit
there could have been no danger of a fall in the value of the rupee. If anything there would have
been a danger of an indefinite appreciation of the rupee, but that was effectually guarded
against by gold having been made general legal tender. A second effect of an absolute limit on the currency would have been to free it from
management by reason of the fact that all question regarding the volume of issues had been
settled once for all.
In these respects, therefore, the gold-exchange
standard is an impairment of the original plan of an inconvertible rupee with fixed limit
of issue supplemented by gold. Again, from the standpoint of controlling the price-level,
the exchange standard cannot be said to have been an improvement on the original plan. Of
course, it is possible to say that such a perversion of the original system is no matter
for regret. Whether gold is a standard of value, or whether fiduciary money is a standard
of value, is a matter of indifference, for neither can be
said to have furnished a stable standard of value. A gold
standard has proved to be as unstable as a paper standard,
because both are susceptible of contraction as well as expansion. All this, no doubt, is true. Nevertheless it is to be noted that
in any monetary system there is no danger of indefinite contraction. [f24]What is to be guarded against is the
possibility of indefinite expansion. The possibility of indefinite expansion, however,
varies with the nature of money. When the standard of value is standard metallic money the
expansion cannot be very great, for the cost of production acts as a sufficient limiting influence. When a standard of value is a convertible paper money the provisions as to reserve
act as a check on its expansion. But when a standard of value consists of a money the
value of which is greater than its cost and is inconvertible,
the currency must be said to be fraught with the fatal
facility of indefinite expansion, which is another name for depreciation or rise of
prices. It cannot, therefore, be said that the Bank Charter Act made no improvement on the
Bank Restriction Act. indeed, it was a great improvement, for it substituted a currency
less liable to expansion in
place of a currency far more liable to expansion. Now the
rupee is a debased coin,[f25] inconvertible, and is unlimited legal tender.
As such, it belongs to that order of money which has
inherent in it the potentiality of indefinite expansion,
i.e. depreciation and rise of prices. As a safeguard against this the better plan was no
doubt the one originally designed, namely of putting a limit
on the issue of rupees, so as to make the Indian currency
system analogous to the English system governed by the Bank
Charter Act of 1844.
If there is any force in the line of reasoning
adopted above, then it is not easy to agree with the opinion entertained by the
Chamberlain Commission of the Exchange Standard. Indeed, it raises a query whether for all
that the Commission said there is not somewhere some weakness in the system likely to
bring about its breakdown. It therefore becomes incumbent to examine the foundations of
that standard from a fresh point of view.
[f1]Report,
P. P. Cd. 7068 of 1913, p. 13.
[f2]
See Chap. IV, supra
[f3]
The rupee branch has been discontinued since that date, on the recommendation of the
Chamberlain Commission.
[f4]Besides,
if the Government falls short of rupees, it has the legal power to convert the gold in the
paper-currency reserve into rupees to replenish the stock.
[f5]
Report, Par, 46
[f6] see supra, Chap IV.
[f7]
Cf., however, R. G. Hawtrey, Currency and Credit,
1919, pp. 302-3.
[f8]
Some witnesses before the Lords Committee on Cash payments, appointed in 1819, raised
doubts whether, having regard to the silver clause of the Act of 1816, resumption of cash
payments was worth while as a means of establishing a gold standard in England. Cf.
particularly the evidence of Mr. Fletcher and also Mr. Mushet before the Committee.
[f9]
See P. P. 400 of 1912.
[f10]
From this point of view the proposition of Prof. Keynes, that the gold value of the rupee
may be fixed irrespective of the cost price of silver, must, having regard to the existing
system of currency, be looked upon as a somewhat unsafe position. Cf. his evidence before
the Indian Currency Committee of 1919,Q. 2,688.
[f11]The
danger involved in this indefinite liability to issue rupee currency was recognised by the
mith Currency Committee of 1919, which recommended that this obligation should be
withdrawn. See Report, par. 68. Of course its
motive was different.
[f12]
Report, par. 182.
[f13]
Currency and Credit, 1919, p. 341.
[f14]
Report, par. 46.
[f15]
Kenynes, Indian Currency and Finance, p. 29.
[f16]
Cf. his review of Keynes in the Quarterly Journal of Economics, February, 1914, p.
[f17]Cf.
Andreades, History of the Bank of England, p.
198.
[f18]
" No single word can convey the full meaning," says Prof. Nicholson, War Finance. 2nd ed., 1918, p. 36.
[f19] A History of American Currency, New York, 1874, p.
116.
[f20]
The Finance Member of the Viceroy's Council, in his Financial Statement for 1908-09 (p.
23, italics not in the original), observed : " Had we complied with the demand
for issues [of gold] without limit, the whole available supply might have been drawn off
in a few weeks...... For these reasons we decided to
stand by our legal rights.... We are not bound to give sovereigns in exchange for
rupee", except at our own convenience. The currency offices were accordingly
instructed not to issue gold in larger
quantities than £ 10,000 to any individual on any one day." These words wore used to
explain the attitude of the Government regarding its sense of obligation as to
convertibility of the rupee in the exchange crisis of 1907! The degree of convertibility
being a matter of administrative discretion it is difficult to define the extent to which
it is given effect to in practice. Official evidence is inclined to impress upon the
public that practically the rupee is convertible. If that is so, why not make it legally convertible. For, if convertibility is
complete in practice a legal convertibility cannot impose upon the Government greater
obligations than what the official evidence suggests the Government to be actually
assuming. It is said that Government does not do so because it is afraid that exchange
speculators will take advantage of it. But why should they not ? Are they not holders of
rupees ? It does not, however, appear to have been adequately realised that this defence
implies that the currency is issued so much beyond the point of the " saturation
" that its value is always on the margin of being affected by an element of
speculation.
[f21]
For reasons giving rise to a premium on gold in terms of the rupee, see Chap. VI. For reasons explaining how there can
be a general depreciation of the rupee without there being a specific depreciation of it
in terms of gold, see end of Chap. VI and
beginning of Chap. VII.
[f22]Both
Lindsay and Probyn had attacked the plan of the Government of India on this score, and had
claimed that their plans were superior because they had at least provided some sort of
convertibility.
[f23]*
In his comparison of the Limping Standard with the Exchange Standard, Prof. Fisher seems
entirely to overlook these considerations. Cf. his Purchasing Power, etc., 1911, pp. 131-32.
[f24]
Cf. Hawtrey, R. G., op. cit., Chap. 1.
[f25] It
is difficult to understand why some writers on Indian currency do not like to admit this
fact. Cf. the discussion on Mr. Madan's paper at the annual meeting of the Indian Economic
Association (Indian Journal of Economics. Vol.
Ill, Part 4, Serial No. 12, p. 560). It is true the debasement of the rupee is not so
obvious as it would have been had it taken the form of continuing the weight and making it
baser or of preserving the same fineness and making it lighter. But, as Harris points out
in his Essay upon Money and Coins (Part II,
Chap. I, par. 8), the " altering the denominations of the coins, without making any
alteration at the Mint or in the coins themselves," " as supposing ninepence, or
as much silver as there is in ninepence, should be called a shilling," is a mode of
debasement not different from that of the rupee, and is virtually the same as the other
two modes of debasement. So viewed it is difficult to avoid the conclusion that the rupee
is a debased coin.